When the Federal Reserve decides that
it wants to increase the amount of currency in circulation, in order
to stimulate the economy, its method of accomplishing this is to buy
securities from its “primary dealer” banks (normally US Treasury
bonds, and recently MBS or mortgage-backed securities). This has the
effect of increasing the cash reserves of those banks, who are
expected to then lend it out into the economy. In short, whenever
new currency is created, it is first used to purchase assets from a
private bank, which will then, it is hoped, lend it out into the
economy for productive purposes.
This method of economic
stimulus, however, has the paradoxical and quite harmful effect of
concentrating wealth in the financial sector while depriving the real
economy (i.e. the people and businesses that actually make things) of
income. The simple reason for this is that all loans made by a bank
must be repaid with interest. To the extent that a loan is
not entirely repaid, there will generally be a forfeiture of property
to the bank to cover their financial losses. In spite of the
occasional bad loan, the net effect of adding currency to the economy
through interest-bearing loans is to transfer financial assets from
real-economy actors to financial-sector actors. A simple model will
make plain why this is the case.
Imagine that we have an economy
composed of three sectors: the productive sector (real economy), the
financial sector (banks), and the government sector. We can imagine
the productive sector as itself composed of households and
businesses, with currency circulating continually between the two:
households buy goods and services from businesses who, in turn, pay
wages back to households.
Now, let us suppose that the productive
sector of the economy has a monthly GDP of $1000. This means that
every month, businesses pay households $1000 in wages which
households then spend at businesses, providing the businesses with
the revenue to pay out in wages at the beginning of the next monthly
cycle. For simplicity, we assume that households spend all of their
income every month and that businesses use all revenue for wages. Essentially,
in our model businesses and households are simply passing $1000 back
and forth between themselves.
Now let's suppose that the population
of our economy grows and additional households are created. In the
absence of any action from the government (which is the only sector
that can add additional currency to the productive sector), the
income per household in the productive sector must necessarily
decline. If we previously had 10 households receiving $100 a piece
per month, and now we have 11 households, each household will now
only receive $90.90 per month. If the government desires to maintain
wage levels at $100 per month, it will need to add an additional $100
to the amount of currency currently circulating in the productive
sector.
In order to do this, the government
gives $100 to the financial sector to lend into the economy.
Assuming the bank lends the entire amount into the economy, in the
month that the government increases the amount of currency, the GDP of
the economy will increase by $100 to $1100 (as households borrow and spend the $100 into circulation), providing enough currency
for each household to once again receive $100 per month. However, his return
to normalcy is short-lived.
Assuming that all loans get repaid,
with interest at the beginning of the next monthly cycle, during the
next month the GDP of our little economy will have to decrease by
$110 (assuming 10% monthly interest, for ease of calculation), in
order to repay the $100 principal plus $10 in interest. This means
that at the start of the following cycle, the amount of currency will
be once again too low to allow incomes to remain at $100 per month.
Only now, the situation will be worse than before the government's
“monetary stimulus,” since the economy's real GDP will have gone
from $1000 to $1100 to $990, giving an average household salary of
$90—90 cents less than before the currency increase. The apparent surge in economic activity and household prosperity is followed quickly by decline for households and businesses alike.
Now, the only way for the household
sector to maintain it's level of income and consumption is to once
again borrow from the financial sector. Only now, instead of
borrowing $100, households must borrow $110 in total from the
financial sector to maintain their income levels (which, remember,
are determined by levels of spending; businesses can't pay wages to
households until households first buy from them). This, of course,
only further worsens the problem as $121 must now be repaid to the
financial sector at the beginning of the following cycle, leaving
only enough money left in the real economy to provide households with
a $79.90 monthly average salary.
It should be easy enough to understand
why it is that an economic stimulus program that depends on private
banks lending new currency into the real economy at interest is a
self-defeating and perverse policy choice (unless, of course, one
happens to work in the financial sector). The only way to add wealth
to the household sector through lending would be to offer the loans
at a negative interest rate: that is, loan $100 and only require $90
back. In the above example the government would give the financial
sector $1000 to loan into the economy at a negative 10% interest
rate, leaving an extra $100 in the economy after the loans had been
repaid.
If the goal of monetary stimulus is to
increase the average household wage, negative interest loans make far
more sense than positive interest loans. Positive interest loans, in
fact, make no sense at all.
No comments:
Post a Comment